Since Vandana Shiva is such a big opponent to the privatization of water, I did a little background research on the subject. Because so far, my impression is that water wars do not take place between countries, but between private coporations and local citizen.
In recent years, neo-liberal policies focused on the privatization of water. Capitalist companies have begun to use especially urban water supply systems as a source for economic growth and profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53). In the countries of the global South, the reforms have reworked the government's provision of public services. At the same time, water privatization has become a controversial discussed issue because it leads to civil protests all over the world (Bakker 2010:3).
In recent years, neo-liberal policies focused on the privatization of water. Capitalist companies have begun to use especially urban water supply systems as a source for economic growth and profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53). In the countries of the global South, the reforms have reworked the government's provision of public services. At the same time, water privatization has become a controversial discussed issue because it leads to civil protests all over the world (Bakker 2010:3).
Privatization is a
transfer of entitlements that can be defined as a “process through
which activities, resources, and the like, which had not been
formally privately owned, managed or organized, are taken away from
whoever or whatever owned them before to a new property configuration
that is based on some form of 'private' ownership or control”
(Swyngedouw 2007:52). The part of this definitions that is most
likely to be a source for discussion is “...are taken away”.
Behind this stands the assumption that resources already belong to
someone before they get privatized.
Since the inception of
urban water systems, there have always been changes in the
public-private partnership. Until the mid of the nineteenth century,
the system was characterized by a range of small private companies
within a city that provided water of varying quality. After that
followed a period of municipalization in which providing essential
public goods was more important than making profit. After the end of
the Second World War and the rising of the nation state, the water
industry became a growing national concern. The governments invested
big in water infrastructure that went along with new jobs, generation
of demand from the private sector and the providing of basic
collective production and consumption goods (Swyngedouw 2007:53f).
Since then, a major
shift in the public/private relationship in the water sector took
place, initiated through the demise of state-led economic growth. The
nations suffered from payment difficulties. The call for greater
competitiveness within the water supply system was accompanied by
privatization tendencies. Investors searched for new investment
possibilities. One possibility was to turn water into capital and
profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53f).
Behind privatization
strategies often stands the wish of the public sector to strengthen
its financial position and to improve competitiveness of the economy.
In terms of developing nations, the idea of privatization includes
structural adjustments and an economic push to stabilize these
nations within the world economy (Glade 1991:2). But at the same
time, a country’s society is more concerned about direct welfare
effects of private over public management than about the economic
growth that comes along with privatization. These welfare effects
could be related to the access to public services and their prices,
job losses or corruption (Chong 2007:3).
In Latin America,
privatization found its way into the relationship between a state and
its citizens after the economic crisis in the 1980s, with the goal to
reduce fiscal deficits and inflation and to liberalize the economy.
Nevertheless, the inhabitants of Latin American countries take a
critical stance towards privatization. According to the
Latinobarometer 2006, only 30 percent of Latin Americans are
“satisfied or very satisfied” with the results of privatization
of public services, “considering price and quality”. Reasons
therefore are among others the fear of social exclusion and the
distrust in economic elites (Chong 2007:1f).
Despite to the negative
view in the population, according to Chong, water privatization
decreases poverty and inequality in most cases, since it leads to a
reduction in common diseases through the improvement of water quality
by privatized companies. However, the nation's governments need to
have strong economic and political capabilities to regulate the
companies and make the lower social class benefit as well (2007:4).
Alberto, Chong.
Privatization for the public good?: Welfare Effects of Private
Intervention in Latin America. Harvard University Press:
Cambridge, MA. 2008. Print
Bakker, Karen.
Privatizing Water. Governance Failure and the World's Urban Water
Crisis. Cornell University Press: Ithaca and London. 2010. Print.
Swyngedouw, Erik.
Dispossessing H²O: the contested terrain of water privatization.
In: Heynen, Nik (ed.). Neoliberal Environments. False promises and
unnatural consequences. Routledge: New York. 2007. Print. pp.
51-62.
Keine Kommentare:
Kommentar veröffentlichen