Sonntag, 15. Dezember 2013
Freitag, 13. Dezember 2013
Mittwoch, 11. Dezember 2013
Water Conflicts in the USA - Part 1
This is to remind ourselves that water is not only scarce in developing countries. For example, there are also parts in the United States where water can become the source for conflicts. This video is about the Rio Grande and how Texas and New Mexico are both dependent on the river.
Montag, 9. Dezember 2013
Treating Water as Common Good
“No to water
privatization – Yes to water as a human right.” (Bakker 2010:2)
In March 2000, these
words were written down on bodies of protestors to the World Water
Forum in The Hague. One of the main arguments of opponents of
privatization is that it is unethical to profit from water, because
it is the essential substance for life. This is why David Harvey
calls water privatization “accumulation of dispossession” (Bakker
2010:2), which leads to social and environmentally inequities.
Perreault points out the dualistic nature of water. It is both a
natural physical entity that becomes a resource through human labor
and the most basic precondition to life: Water is “as dependent on
social institutions and labors as it is on climate and geology”
(2004:269).
The opponents also
criticize the power private investors gain through controlling such a
basic, vital good (Chong 2007:2). One of the main opponents of the
privatization of water is Shiva Vandana. She sees water as a sacred
that cannot be owned as a private property or sold. Water is no human
invention, it cannot be bound. She has a clear opinion toward the IMF
and the World Bank: “Denying poor people access to water by
privatizing water distribution or polluting wells and rivers is also
terrorism... [terrorists] are hiding behind the privatization
conditionality’s of the IMF and World Bank” (Shiva 2002: xiv;
37). Water needs to be a collective right and a collective management
like it is treated by indigenous communities, for example in India
(Shiva 2002:12). Moreover, Shiva defines water crisis as an
ecological crisis that cannot be solved through market mechanism,
because higher prices won't lead to conversation (2002:15ff). The
representatives of the 'water as common good' approach also argue
that government-run water supply systems work as effective as private
ones and can offer lower tariffs on top because they have access to
cheaper forms of finance (Bakker 2010:2).
Alberto, Chong.
Privatization for the public good?: Welfare Effects of Private
Intervention in Latin America. Harvard University Press:
Cambridge, MA. 2008. Print
Bakker, Karen.
Privatizing Water. Governance Failure and the World's Urban Water
Crisis. Cornell University Press: Ithaca and London. 2010. Print.
Swyngedouw, Erik.
Dispossessing H²O: the contested terrain of water privatization.
In: Heynen, Nik (ed.). Neoliberal Environments. False promises and
unnatural consequences. Routledge: New York. 2007. Print. pp.
51-62.
Samstag, 7. Dezember 2013
Treating Water as Commodity
From my least entry we know that water conflicts mostly arise between adherents of two opponent ideologies of how to treat water. Today I am going to talk about the "water as commodity" approach and my next entry will be about the "water as common good" approach.
At the end of the last century, international companies like Bechtel or Vivendi expanded their ownerships of water supply systems. The private sector started taking over more and more government owned systems. The nations considered market-based water sectors as the best possibility to face the world's increasing water crisis (Bakker 2010:2). With this idea, they followed the so-called 'market paradigm' that explains water crisis as the result from the absence of water trade: “If water could be moved and distributed freely through free markets, this paradigm holds, it would be transferred to regions of scarcity, and higher prices would lead to conversation” (Shiva 2002: 14). In other words, treating water as commodity leads to an adjustment of water demand and supply. The force of the free market can solve the problem of the water crisis.
At the end of the last century, international companies like Bechtel or Vivendi expanded their ownerships of water supply systems. The private sector started taking over more and more government owned systems. The nations considered market-based water sectors as the best possibility to face the world's increasing water crisis (Bakker 2010:2). With this idea, they followed the so-called 'market paradigm' that explains water crisis as the result from the absence of water trade: “If water could be moved and distributed freely through free markets, this paradigm holds, it would be transferred to regions of scarcity, and higher prices would lead to conversation” (Shiva 2002: 14). In other words, treating water as commodity leads to an adjustment of water demand and supply. The force of the free market can solve the problem of the water crisis.
Representatives of the
‘water as commodity’ approach are certain that private companies
perform better than public services in terms of efficiency, finance
and expertise. They argue that water should be treated as an economic
good to guarantee water conservation or reduction of pollution. The
problems of government management of urban water supplies are “low
coverage rates, low rates of cost recovery, low tariffs,
underinvestment, deteriorating infrastructure, overstaffing,
inefficient management, and unresponsiveness to the needs of the
poor” (Bakker 2010:2). In short: according to the 'water as
commodity' view, the government has failed and it is irresponsible to
not let private companies take over (Bakker 2010:2).
The World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund regard privatization of government
services as one way to reduce poverty. To achieve the MDG, they
strongly support privatization of water. Private sector investors
underline the under performance of the public sector in many
developing countries to legitimize the commodification of water
(Morvaridi 2008:70). Behind this course of action stands the
neo-liberal assumption development can be initiated by market-led
measures such as free trade, privatization and minimal state
intervention (Moravidi 2008:67). Neo-liberals see individuals as
“rational economic actors, who operate in the market for utility
maximization and are motivated by self-interest” (Moravidi
2008:69). This assumption leads them to the conclusion that public
goods and community are not necessary because every individual is
responsible for his/her own poverty (Moravidi 2008:69).
Morvaridi argues that it
is problematic to give water an economic value, because at the end
the poor have to pay charges they cannot afford. In addition, it is
the duty of the state to guarantee its citizen access to human rights
and basic standards of living, as they are put down in the Universal
Declaration of Human Rights (Moravidi 2008:70).
Bakker, Karen.
Privatizing Water. Governance Failure and the World's Urban Water
Crisis. Cornell University Press: Ithaca and London. 2010. Print.
Morvaridi, Behrooz.
Social Justice and Development. Ch.3: Neoliberalism and Social
Justice. Palgrave MacMillian: New York. 2008. Print. pp. 67-106.
Shiva, Vandana. Water
Wars. Privatization, Pollution, and Profit. South End Press:
Cambridge, MA. 2002. Print.
Donnerstag, 5. Dezember 2013
Water Privatization
Since Vandana Shiva is such a big opponent to the privatization of water, I did a little background research on the subject. Because so far, my impression is that water wars do not take place between countries, but between private coporations and local citizen.
In recent years, neo-liberal policies focused on the privatization of water. Capitalist companies have begun to use especially urban water supply systems as a source for economic growth and profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53). In the countries of the global South, the reforms have reworked the government's provision of public services. At the same time, water privatization has become a controversial discussed issue because it leads to civil protests all over the world (Bakker 2010:3).
In recent years, neo-liberal policies focused on the privatization of water. Capitalist companies have begun to use especially urban water supply systems as a source for economic growth and profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53). In the countries of the global South, the reforms have reworked the government's provision of public services. At the same time, water privatization has become a controversial discussed issue because it leads to civil protests all over the world (Bakker 2010:3).
Privatization is a
transfer of entitlements that can be defined as a “process through
which activities, resources, and the like, which had not been
formally privately owned, managed or organized, are taken away from
whoever or whatever owned them before to a new property configuration
that is based on some form of 'private' ownership or control”
(Swyngedouw 2007:52). The part of this definitions that is most
likely to be a source for discussion is “...are taken away”.
Behind this stands the assumption that resources already belong to
someone before they get privatized.
Since the inception of
urban water systems, there have always been changes in the
public-private partnership. Until the mid of the nineteenth century,
the system was characterized by a range of small private companies
within a city that provided water of varying quality. After that
followed a period of municipalization in which providing essential
public goods was more important than making profit. After the end of
the Second World War and the rising of the nation state, the water
industry became a growing national concern. The governments invested
big in water infrastructure that went along with new jobs, generation
of demand from the private sector and the providing of basic
collective production and consumption goods (Swyngedouw 2007:53f).
Since then, a major
shift in the public/private relationship in the water sector took
place, initiated through the demise of state-led economic growth. The
nations suffered from payment difficulties. The call for greater
competitiveness within the water supply system was accompanied by
privatization tendencies. Investors searched for new investment
possibilities. One possibility was to turn water into capital and
profit (Swyngedouw 2007:53f).
Behind privatization
strategies often stands the wish of the public sector to strengthen
its financial position and to improve competitiveness of the economy.
In terms of developing nations, the idea of privatization includes
structural adjustments and an economic push to stabilize these
nations within the world economy (Glade 1991:2). But at the same
time, a country’s society is more concerned about direct welfare
effects of private over public management than about the economic
growth that comes along with privatization. These welfare effects
could be related to the access to public services and their prices,
job losses or corruption (Chong 2007:3).
In Latin America,
privatization found its way into the relationship between a state and
its citizens after the economic crisis in the 1980s, with the goal to
reduce fiscal deficits and inflation and to liberalize the economy.
Nevertheless, the inhabitants of Latin American countries take a
critical stance towards privatization. According to the
Latinobarometer 2006, only 30 percent of Latin Americans are
“satisfied or very satisfied” with the results of privatization
of public services, “considering price and quality”. Reasons
therefore are among others the fear of social exclusion and the
distrust in economic elites (Chong 2007:1f).
Despite to the negative
view in the population, according to Chong, water privatization
decreases poverty and inequality in most cases, since it leads to a
reduction in common diseases through the improvement of water quality
by privatized companies. However, the nation's governments need to
have strong economic and political capabilities to regulate the
companies and make the lower social class benefit as well (2007:4).
Alberto, Chong.
Privatization for the public good?: Welfare Effects of Private
Intervention in Latin America. Harvard University Press:
Cambridge, MA. 2008. Print
Bakker, Karen.
Privatizing Water. Governance Failure and the World's Urban Water
Crisis. Cornell University Press: Ithaca and London. 2010. Print.
Swyngedouw, Erik.
Dispossessing H²O: the contested terrain of water privatization.
In: Heynen, Nik (ed.). Neoliberal Environments. False promises and
unnatural consequences. Routledge: New York. 2007. Print. pp.
51-62.
Dienstag, 3. Dezember 2013
India Water Crisis - Part 2
In this video, Vandana Shiva talks about the roots
of the water crisis in India. She is a well-known environmental
activist and anti-globalization author and wrote the book "Water
Wars. Privatization, Pollution and Profit" that criticizes
harshly the privatization of water.
According to her, the roots of the water crisis in
India lie with the introduction of non-sustainable technology and the
mining of groundwater.
Sonntag, 1. Dezember 2013
India Water Crisis - Part 1
India might have enough rainfall for its whole population, but the counrty is facing a water crisi nevertheless. One of the problem is that water is taken away from poor areas to fill water tanks and swimming pools in richter cities like Delhi.
Abonnieren
Posts (Atom)